Skip top navigation

Recession of 1937–38

May 1937–June 1938
Lasting from May 1937 until June 1938, this recession was America’s third-worst downturn of the 20th century. With real GDP dropping 10 percent and unemployment hitting 20 percent, it was less severe than the recessions of 1920 and 1929.
Men wearing sandwich boards reading "I voted for ham and eggs" and "I believed the banks" walk down a Los Angeles street, Oct. 24, 1938. 
Men wearing sandwich boards reading "I voted for ham and eggs" and "I believed the banks" walk down a Los Angeles street, Oct. 24, 1938.  (Photo: Associated Press)
by Patricia Waiwood, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

The 1937 recession occurred during the recovery from the Great Depression. The recovery began in 1933 and culminated during World War II. The recession of 1937 lived quietly in the Great Depression’s shadow, that is, until the 2008 crisis rekindled interest in mid-recovery contractions. Similarities between the recent recession and the Great Depression have piqued interest in the “recession within [the] Depression.” Policymakers are hoping to learn from this historical episode in order to avoid repeating it.

According to the National Bureau of Economic Research, the 1937 contraction, which lasted from May 1937 until June 1938, was America’s third-worst recession of the twentieth century, paling in comparison to the 1920 and 1929 downturns. A few statistics reveal the severity of the 1937 recession: Real GDP fell 10 percent. Unemployment, which had declined considerably after 1933, hit 20 percent. Finally, industrial production fell 32 percent (Bordo and Haubrich 2012).

According to the literature on the subject, the possible causes of that recession were a contraction in the money supply caused by Federal Reserve and Treasury Department policies and contractionary fiscal policies. In 1936, to prevent an “injurious credit expansion,” Fed policymakers doubled reserve requirement ratios to soak up banks’ excess reserves (which is money above the amount banks were required to hold as a fraction of customers’ deposits) (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1936). Excess reserves averaged about $500 million in 1933. Remarkably, they swelled from $859 million in December 1933 to over $3.3 billion in December 1935 (Roose 1954).

A question arises: Why did banks hold such large quantities of reserves? A 2010 piece published by the Atlanta Fed answers this question (Dwyer 2010). Uncertainty, associated with runs on the banking system from 1929 to 1933 and the ensuing economic problems, probably explains part of the increase in excess reserves. Friedman and Schwartz (1963) share the view that banks increased their preferences for reserves in the wake of the 1929 crash. Low interest rates also contributed to the high level of excess reserves and may well have been a more important reason for the increase of excess reserves. The reason is that when short-term rates are low, it is less costly to hold large amounts of non-interest-earning reserves than to repeatedly incur the fixed cost of adjusting.

The Fed’s contractionary policy was complemented by the Treasury’s decision, in late June 1936, to sterilize gold inflows in order to reduce excess reserves. The sterilization policy severed the link between gold inflows and monetary expansion. By preventing gold inflows from becoming part of the monetary base, this policy abruptly halted what had been a strong monetary expansion. Friedman and Schwartz (1963, 544) maintained that “The combined impact of the rise in reserve requirements and—no less important—the Treasury gold-sterilization program first sharply reduced the rate of increase in the monetary stock and then converted it into a decline.” This brief essay is limited to noting that there is an ongoing debate about which policy played the greater contractionary role.

Fiscal policy hardly helped. The Social Security payroll tax debuted in 1937, on top of the tax increase mandated by the Revenue Act of 1935. The changes in the net effect of government spending have been heavily emphasized as a cause of both the recession and the revival of 1937‒38. For example, in 1939, Marriner Eccles asserted that the “too rapid withdrawal of the government’s stimulus…accompanied by other important factors…[led to the] rapid deflation in the fall of 1937, which continued until the present spending program of the government was begun last summer” (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1939). The acceptance of this viewpoint among high-ranking officials gives added significance to an investigation of government fiscal policy.

Federal Reserve Board members at the October 19, 1937 Meeting. In the photograph, left to right: M.S. Szymczak, John McKee, Ronald Ransom, Vice Chairman; Marriner Eccles, Chairman; and Chester C. Davis.
Federal Reserve Board members at the October 19, 1937 Meeting. In the photograph, left to right: M.S. Szymczak, John McKee, Ronald Ransom, Vice Chairman; Marriner Eccles, Chairman; and Chester C. Davis. (Harris & Ewing photo via Library of Congress Prints & Photographs Division, LC-DIG-hec-23488)

The recession ended after the Fed rolled back reserve requirements, the Treasury stopped sterilizing gold inflows and desterilized all remaining gold that had been sterilized since December 1936, and the Roosevelt administration began pursuing expansionary fiscal policies. The recovery from 1938 to 1942 was spectacular: Output grew by 49 percent, fueled by gold inflows from Europe and a major defense buildup.

Concerning the recovery from the recent financial crisis, the 1937 episode provides a “cautionary tale,” wrote economist Christina Romer, against withdrawing economic support too early: A return to economic decline, or even panic, could follow. Chicago Fed President Charles Evans expressed a similar view in 2012: “There is a natural tendency for policymakers to pull back on accommodation too early before the real rate of interest has fallen to low enough levels. Such errors happened in 1937 when the Fed prematurely withdrew accommodation.” In short, the 1937 recession warns us to proceed with caution.


Bibliography

Bordo, Michael D., and Joseph G. Haubrich. “Deep Recessions, Fast Recoveries, and Financial Crises: Evidence from the American Record.” NBER Working Paper 18194, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, June 2012.

Dwyer, Gerald P. “Excess Reserves in the 1930s: A Precautionary Tale.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Notes from the Vault, January 2010

Eccles, Marriner S. “Radio address.” January 23, 1939 via FRASER.

Evans, Charles, “Managing Monetary Policy Risks,” Speech delivered at the Indiana Bankers Association, Economic Outlook Forum 2012, Indianapolis, IN, January 13, 2012.

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Circular on Supplement to Regulation D, July 16, 1936, via FRASER.

Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.

Romer, Christina, “The Lessons of 1937,” The Economist, June 18, 2009.

Roose, Kenneth D. The Economics of Recession and Revival: An Interpretation of 1937-38. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1954.

Velde, Francois R. “The Recession of 1937: A Cautionary Tale.” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives 33, no. 4 (November 2009): 16-37.


Written as of November 22, 2013. See disclaimer.